Author: admin

  • Building coalitions for climate transition and nature restoration

    Building coalitions for climate transition and nature restoration

    Executive summary

    Global climate and biodiversity outcomes will largely be determined in emerging and developing economies (EMDEs). We propose a four-pillar strategy to support climate and nature preservation in line with the economic interests of both developing and advanced countries. This would move beyond voluntary pledges to embed climate and nature objectives into the structures of trade, finance and industrial policy, creating a self-reinforcing system of cooperation and reducing the net costs of the green transition.

    Under Pillar 1, a coalition of advanced and developing countries would link tiered carbon pricing with a common carbon border adjustment mechanism (CBAM). Pillar 2 would create a climate-finance coalition to decarbonise the power sectors of developing countries. Pillar 3 would involve partnerships to develop clean energy-intensive industrial production stages in developing economies with rich renewables endowments; these would feed into the supply chains of the European Union and other energy-importing advanced economies. Pillar 4 would redesign markets to create scalable and credible mechanisms to fund carbon removals. Technology-based removals can be incentivised through the introduction of clean-up certificates into the EU emissions trading system, while nature-based removals would require improved market design centred on a new asset class: nature shares.

    The four pillars reinforce each other. A multi-country CBAM and carbon pricing coalition (Pillar 1) would reduce the cost of financing power sector decarbonisation (Pillar 2). Linking EMDE membership of the CBAM and carbon-pricing coalition to financial support for the decarbonisation of power sectors would also make it more attractive for EMDEs to adopt carbon prices. Decarbonisation of power sectors (Pillar 2) would be a precondition for developing clean, highly energy-intensive industry in renewables-rich EMDEs (Pillar 3).

    The Pillar 1 coalition should include the EU, China and as many other countries as possible. Advanced countries and China could underpin the Pillar 2 financier coalition. Pillar 3 would involve the EU and potentially other energy-poor advanced countries, along with EMDEs that are richly endowed with renewables. Pillar 4 would include the main custodians of the planet’s natural capital. Enabling these coalitions will require EU leadership.

    This Policy Brief distils some of the main messages of the Paris Report 2025, a joint initiative by Bruegel and CEPR (Pisani-Ferry et al, 2025). This year’s focus is on accelerating the energy transition and restoring nature in emerging and developing economies. We thank all Paris Report contributors, and Patrick Bolton, Kim Clausing, Ignacio Garcia Bercero, Heather Grabbe, Alissa Kleinnijenhuis, Matthias Kalkuhl, José Scheinkman and Simone Tagliapietra for comments on an earlier draft.

     

    1 Introduction

    The planet’s future depends increasingly on emerging and developing economies. Advanced economies continue to matter because of their higher per-capita emissions, their shares of global trade and finance, and their influence through research, technology and diplomacy; but their share in global greenhouse gas emissions is shrinking. Success in stopping global warming and halting biodiversity loss hinges on whether countries such as India, Indonesia, Brazil and South Africa adopt low-carbon, nature-positive development paths, and if they do so quickly. The same applies to China, which is both the world’s top emitter of CO2 and the country at the forefront of the green industrial revolution.

    Geopolitical fragmentation, shifting priorities and a hostile United States administration are slowing the transition to a more sustainable economic model in line with the landmark Paris Climate Agreement of 2015. With climate and nature degradation accelerating, governments that understand the importance of climate and nature actions – still in the majority – are faced with hard questions. Recent international discussions on climate change mitigation and the preservation of biodiversity have centred on ambitious targets and the closing of funding gaps. These remain important topics for negotiation but are no longer sufficient. Instead, a broader approach is required to connect mitigation with adaptation and the preservation of nature.

    This calls for deeper cooperation among countries with common interests in trade, clean energy and nature. Recognising that this group will for now not include the US, we propose coalitions of the willing for climate, biodiversity, trade and finance – wherever mutual interests can still align.

    The European Union will need to play a special role in the creation of these coalitions. Because of its strong consensus around climate science, an ambitious decarbonisation agenda and a functioning, expanding emissions trading system that has delivered high carbon prices, it has both the credibility and the responsibility to lead, engaging emerging markets and developing economies (EMDEs) and building financing alliances with other advanced countries.

     

    2 The case for action

    In a darkening geopolitical landscape, the pace of technological innovation is a bright spot. Renewable energy and other green technologies have rapidly gained cost competitiveness and scale. Most new renewable power is now cheaper than fossil fuel alternatives. The IEA (2024), IRENA (2024) and Lazard (2024), among others, have shown that the levelised cost of electricity (LCOE) of unsubsidised solar and wind is often lower than that of fossil fuel-based electricity generation, especially when considering new power plant construction.

    Solar photovoltaic (PV) costs have plummeted to roughly $0.04 per kWh, making solar power more than 50 percent cheaper than generation from fossil fuels or nuclear plants (IRENA, 2024). Even accounting for network and backup costs, this is major progress that is bound to affect the energy pecking order. This dramatic cost decline, alongside improvements in wind turbines and battery technology, means clean technologies offer better economic returns than coal or gas. In dollar terms, investment in renewables now outpaces fossil electricity investment by ten to one, with more investment in solar than in all other power sources combined. Year-on-year global growth in electricity generation from solar PV was double the growth from all fossil fuels combined in 2024. Other green technologies are also scaling quickly. Meanwhile, electric vehicle sales have risen from 3 million units in 2020 to 17 million units in 2024 (IEA, 2025).

    But despite these developments, investment in new coal-fired power plants continues, particularly in China, which approved 106 gigawatts of new coal power capacity in 2022 alone – four times the amount approved in 2021. Reasons for this include concerns about supply security, local support for coal and the high upfront cost of investment in renewables that many countries find difficult to finance. Unless retired early, these coal plants will remain in operation for decades, locking in emissions far beyond 2030. Meanwhile, the global vehicle fleet remains overwhelmingly dependent on fossil fuels: in 2024, more than 95 percent of vehicles in circulation still had internal combustion engines.

    Consequently, climate policies and trajectories are far off the path needed to reach emissions targets compatible with the Paris Agreement’s objective of limiting global warming to 1.5 degrees Celsius above pre-industrial levels. Continuing with today’s policies is projected to lead to about 2.7°C of warming by 2100. Moreover, aggregate projections mask stark differences between advanced and developing economies. Emissions in most advanced economies have already peaked and steady declines have begun. In contrast, emissions in many EMDEs are still rising, driven by economic and population growth and continued heavy reliance on coal, oil and gas.

    Figure 1: Historical emissions, 1970-2023, and requirements for reaching net zero in 2050

    Source: Grabbe et al (2025). Note: several countries, including China and India, have set less ambitious targets. * EMDEs includes China. The 2050 projection is given for EMDEs as a whole and not separately for China. BAU = business as usual; NDC = Nationally Determined Contribution; LULUCF = land use, land-use change and forestry.

    As of 2023, EMDEs (including China) accounted for roughly two-thirds of global emissions. Their share is expected to grow further as they contribute the bulk of new emissions. Advanced economies account for a shrinking portion of annual emissions (for example, the EU and United Kingdom together now contribute only about 8 percent of global emissions). Reaching global net zero emissions by 2050 requires a sharp break with the current emissions trend in EMDEs (Figure 1). Limiting global warming to 1.5°C would require an even more radical break, consistent with reaching global net-zero emissions by the mid-to-late 2030s rather than 2050.

    EMDEs are also custodians of much of the planet’s natural capital, so that collective climate outcomes are intertwined with how those countries manage nature and biodiversity. Many of the world’s critical carbon sinks and biodiversity hotspots (including tropical forests and wetlands) are located in developing regions across Latin America, Africa and Asia. These ecosystems bolster climate resilience by absorbing CO₂ and providing a buffer against extreme weather. Conversely, their destruction would accelerate climate change and undermine adaptation efforts. Nature-based solutions, such as reforestation and ecosystem restoration, could provide 20 percent to 30 percent of the emissions reductions needed to limit warming to 1.5°C (chapter 7 in IPCC, 2022). However, continued deforestation or ecosystem collapse (for instance, of the Amazon rainforest) would release vast amounts of carbon and destabilise regional climates. Climate change and biodiversity loss are mutually reinforcing: climate change is now a leading driver of biodiversity loss, and in turn the erosion of biodiversity undermines natural carbon sinks and ecosystem resilience. It follows that preserving nature – alongside cutting emissions – is essential for climate stability and nature sustainability.

    The costs of the green transition and of restoring/protecting nature in emerging economies are often disproportionately high relative to their GDPs and fiscal capacities. Our best guess estimates of the investments needed are far above current investment levels in EMDEs (excluding China). In practice, annual clean-energy investment in developing regions would need to more than quadruple from 2022 levels by 2030. This would be unprecedented. It reflects the reality that many EMDE economies are both carbon-intensive (hence requiring more investment to decarbonise) and growing rapidly (hence needing more energy infrastructure overall).

    Financing these investments is challenging because of the high cost of capital in EMDEs. Capital for clean energy projects is considerably more expensive in developing markets, reflecting higher macroeconomic risks, regulatory and political uncertainty, and less developed financial systems (Berglof et al, 2025; Fornaro et al, 2025; Sen, 2025). For example, in 2021 the real cost of capital for a utility-scale solar PV project was about 3 percent in Europe and the US, but roughly 7 percent in India and Mexico, over 9 percent in Brazil and as high as 10 percent to 15 percent in sub-Saharan African countries (IEA, 2023). This steep disparity in financing costs greatly inflates the levelised cost of renewable energy in emerging economies, often offsetting their natural advantages, such as abundant solar irradiation.

    International climate finance is supposed to help bridge this gap, but it remains insufficient. Support has fallen short against lofty pledges. In late 2024, advanced countries agreed in principle (the ‘Baku commitment’) to provide about $300 billion per year in climate finance for developing nations, but the flows in 2022 were around $100 billion. The gaps in nature conservation are equally mind-boggling. To reverse biodiversity decline, the Kunming-Montreal Global Biodiversity Framework (2025) calls for a financing gap of about $700 billion per year to be closed. Of this, $500 billion per year should come from phasing out harmful subsidies, reflecting the fact that, at present, nature conservation spending is vastly overshadowed by expenditures that harm nature.

    One of the main problems with the widely cited finance gap estimates is that they are rarely accompanied by credible strategies to close them. Instead, these figures are often presented as arguments to mobilise funding, particularly from the private sector or through blended finance mechanisms. However, as the disparity between estimated needs and actual flows increases, the effectiveness of gap estimates as mobilisation tools diminishes. Rather than galvanising action, they risk fostering resignation – or worse, a new form of denial, whereby the evidence from climate science may no longer be questioned but the policies needed to combat climate change will. In wealthier countries, particularly those in temperate climate zones, this can lead to a quiet acceptance of failure and a shift in focus to adaptation, the implicit message being that the battle has been lost.

    In addition, global collective action to combat climate change faces several new problems:

    • A disjointed approach to address highly connected issues: although the containment of global warming and the preservation of nature are linked in multiple ways, they are mostly tackled separately.
    • The fraying of multilateralism: the previous remedy to the shortcomings of a disjointed approach would have been to embrace a more holistic strategy, yet nationalism and geo-political tensions hamper the search for encompassing solutions.
    • A lack of adequate incentives: developing countries (for their mitigation efforts) and advanced countries (for their contributions to the financing of these efforts) both face collective action problems, but incentives are not adequately aligned.

    To address these problems, a robust and realistic architecture is needed. In the current geopolitical context, such an architecture must be flexible, recognising that a requirement for agreement by consensus will hold the transition back and will give too much say to those that are dragging their feet. Coalitions of countries that are ready to move more quickly offer the best way forward, and are more likely to align incentives. We propose a redesign based on four pillars:

    3 A four-pillar strategy

    3.1 Pillar 1: a plurilateral carbon pricing coalition with a common CBAM

    The 2015 Paris Agreement achieved near-universal participation, with 196 countries agreeing to commit to climate action. This broad involvement was unprecedented, particularly compared to earlier agreements such as the Kyoto Protocol, in which not all developed nations participated (Guérin and Tubiana, 2025). Unlike previous top-down approaches, Paris allowed countries to determine their own climate commitments, making it politically feasible for many countries to join and offer pledges according to their capabilities. EMDEs could present both unconditional and conditional targets, explicitly linking goals to financial support from rich countries. Subsequent climate summits have also introduced systematic transparency measures, requiring regular progress reports on emissions reductions, with peer review and pressure.

    Ten years on, the Paris Agreement pledges formulated by countries (their Nationally Determined Contributions, or NDCs) make it possible to assess if they add up to the level of effort required to halt global warming (they do not). However, there is no binding enforcement mechanism to ensure that countries meet their commitments. The Paris Agreement cannot adequately address the free-rider problem associated with emissions: the benefits of emissions reductions are global, but the costs are borne by each country.

    The second withdrawal of the United States from the Paris Agreement, in January 2025 at the direction of the re-elected President Trump, was a significant setback. But it is also a strategic opportunity for other nations to strengthen international climate cooperation. The absence of the US from global climate negotiations could enable the European Union and other major global economies such as China, Brazil and India to agree ambitious and coherent international climate strategies, without needing to accommodate constraints created by US domestic politics and preferences. At the same time, it is important that any agreement should be open to future US participation.

    Scaling-up effective climate action requires a stronger link between climate policies and trade. We propose, building on Clausing et al (2025), that international collaboration take the form of an open and inclusive ‘climate coalition’. Membership obligations would include:

    1. Adoption of a tiered carbon pricing mechanism; and

    2. Adoption of a common carbon border adjustment mechanism (and no carbon border adjustment within the coalition).

    The EU decision to introduce a carbon border adjustment mechanism (CBAM) would be an incentive for countries to join the club of climate-ambitious countries. They would gain CBAM exemption, along with possible additional incentives involving technology transfer, climate finance, technical assistance, and clean energy trade liberalisation. Club members would commit to enforce domestic carbon pricing through taxation or equivalent emissions trading systems. They would also adopt CBAMs that impose tariffs equivalent to their domestic carbon prices on imports from non-member nations. This would reduce carbon leakage and maintain competitive fairness.

    Importantly, Clausing et al (2025) propose that participation be structured through a tiered carbon pricing system, such as that proposed by the International Monetary Fund (Parry et al, 2021). For example, lower-income countries could implement lower carbon price floors (eg €25 per tonne), middle-income countries would be requested to adopt a higher, but still moderate level (eg €50 per tonne) and higher-income economies would have higher rates (at least €75 per tonne), with prices adjusted regularly for inflation. Other variations, including differentiation between lower and upper middle-income countries, could also be considered.

    This differentiated approach aligns with the principle of common but differentiated responsibilities, a cornerstone of previous global climate agreements, and addresses equity concerns by mitigating potential economic impacts on developing nations. The differentiated schedule should serve as a transitional measure, with carbon tax rates increasing as countries achieve higher levels of income. This expectation of carbon price convergence should reduce incentives for carbon-intensive industries to relocate to jurisdictions with lower carbon prices. Both the levels of the tiers and the pace of convergence would be subject to negotiation (Clausing et al, 2025).

    The coalition would initially focus on the carbon-intensive goods included in the EU CBAM: aluminium, iron and steel, cement, fertilisers and hydrogen production. These industries comprise a significant share of global carbon emissions (about 20 percent), including both direct emissions and the emissions from the electricity used in their production. But the CBAM could be enlarged if similar measures are adopted by other countries, for example in East Asia, and be broadened if other goods end up being added to the intermediate products of the initial list.

    The size and economic value of the market created by the club will determine the incentives to join. The economic value would determine the club’s ability to internalise the climate benefits of collective mitigation efforts.

    This proposed climate club would complement the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change Conference of the Parties (COP) process by deepening collaboration among coalition members – primarily because it relies on reciprocity and meaningful incentives rather than voluntary commitments and peer pressure. Countries would gain economic benefits from participation and the reciprocal structure would incentivise sustained participation and climate action, while addressing carbon leakage and competitiveness concerns.

    A viable coalition should quickly expand from the EU and its main suppliers to other large countries, including China, Korea, Japan, India, South Africa and Brazil. These countries are, of course, at very different stages of development, and their respective incentives will need to be calibrated carefully. In addition to a tiered schedule for carbon pricing, the design should include commitments to technology transfer and financial support for green transitions in lower-income countries. In light of concerns about industrial overcapacity in sectors such as steel, it may also require an agreement to limit or eliminate subsidies. The EU would need to play a leading role in establishing this framework.

    3.2 Pillar 2: Scaled-up climate finance conditional on effective decarbonisation commitments

    The current commitments of advanced countries to finance EMDE decarbonisation are insufficient and are not matched by developing country commitments to decarbonise. Therefore, the implicit contract between North and South can (and in many instances does) result in an unproductive exchange of false promises: advanced countries pretend they will finance decarbonisation in the South, while developing countries pretend that they will decarbonise.

    A way out of this conundrum would be to form ‘climate finance coalitions’ involving subsets of advanced countries willing to fund decarbonisation in the South and subsets of developing countries willing to decarbonise their economies if given access to funding on reasonable terms (Bolton and Kleinnijenhuis, 2025). This mutual commitment would be in the self-interest of all participating countries: all would gain from the avoidance of physical, health and economic damage thanks to lower emissions in EMDEs, while economic benefits would be roughly in proportion to countries’ GDP. As a result, fiscal support for the decarbonisation of EMDEs (except China) would be in the economic interest of advanced countries and China, even if EMDEs do not contribute (Bolton and Kleinnijenhuis, 2025).

    The cost of funding developing country decarbonisation as a share of the GDP of the financier coalition would depend on the size of that coalition. A coalition of all advanced countries and China would pay less than 0.2 percent of GDP annually for EMDE power-sector decarbonisation consistent with the Paris 1.5°C objective. For a funding coalition that excludes the US but includes China, the EU, Canada, Japan, South Korea and some additional smaller industrial partners, the fiscal burden would be about 0.2 percent of GDP. If China is also excluded from the financier coalition, the cost would rise to 0.3 percent of GDP/year.

    The greater the economic damage from climate change, the smaller the critical mass of participants would need to be for coalition financing to be profitable. But even if global economic damage (the social cost of carbon) were relatively low ($190/tCO2, as assumed by Rennert et al, 2022), a financier coalition consisting of the EU and advanced countries except the US would benefit economically from financing the decarbonisation of most of the largest developing country power-sector emitters. If the US or China were to join, the coalition would find it in its interest to finance the decarbonisation of almost all developing country emitters. If the assumed damages are significantly higher, as argued by Bilal and Känzig (2025), large entities including the EU, China (and the US) would find it profitable to embark on decarbonisation support alone, even if not joined by other partners.

    Under the Paris Agreement, all signatories must offer new NDCs at COP30 in Brazil in November 2025. With the next versions not due until 2030, this set of NDCs represents the last chance to put emissions on a net-zero consistent path. The EU and its climate finance coalition partners should offer conditional fiscal support to all developing countries (except China and oil and gas producers) that are willing to commit to net-zero consistent decarbonisation of their power sectors. While only accounting for about 40 percent of developing countries’ emissions, power-sector decarbonisation is a necessary step for the decarbonisation of industry and transport.

    3.3 Pillar 3: Green industrial partnerships between the EU and developing countries

    Europe currently imports most of its oil and gas at relatively high cost. The continent’s transition to clean energy will end its dependency on imported fossil fuels, but not its relative energy scarcity (McWilliams et al, 2025). Europe is not well-endowed in green energy. Limited land availability and a relatively poor solar potential (except in Southern Europe) imply that the cost of producing electricity will be higher than in countries on the other side of the Mediterranean, in the Middle East or in Africa. Nuclear power can help, but not to the point of eliminating Europe’s structural cost disadvantage, as nuclear is relatively expensive compared to renewables once the possibility of electricity storage is factored in.

    As a result, Europe will remain an energy importer in the medium and possibly long terms. However, transporting electricity is much more costly than transporting fossil fuels, even taking into account the possibility of producing hydrogen and transporting it by sea or through pipelines. In contrast, energy-intensive intermediate products in the value chains of the chemical and steel industries, such as ammonia, fertilisers, methanol and reduced iron, can be easily and cost-effectively transported by sea.

    For this reason, the green transition is bound to transform the international division of labour along value chains. Developing country exporters of primary products such as iron ore are likely to move down the value chain and export processed products, such as direct reduced iron, instead of raw commodities. Consequently, some upstream segments of European energy-intensive industries (EIIs) would move South. This restructuring of global value chains would be economically efficient and would help the industrialisation of the South.

    To the extent that energy-intensive intermediate inputs, such as ammonia or direct reduced iron, are produced with green electricity or green hydrogen, it would also lead to significant greenhouse gases emission reductions.

    This leaves two important questions unanswered: 

    1. How to ensure that the migration of energy-intensive production supports Europe’s own green industrialisation goals and, more broadly, its efforts to improve its competitiveness and its economic security; and
    2. How to ensure that it results in global emissions reductions, rather than simply carbon leakage from the EU to the Global South.

    McWilliams et al (2025) seek to answer both questions. On the first, they argue that the direct value added and employment loss of the relocation of energy-intensive intermediate products to the South would be modest. In Germany, EIIs account for most industrial energy demand but only 5 percent of manufacturing wages and 6 percent of the value added. The upstream segments of those industries represent a fraction of those numbers. At the same time, relocating these production stages should not only boost the competitiveness of downstream EII segments, but also industrial competitiveness more broadly, by reducing energy costs. Substituting domestic production of ammonia, methanol and reduced iron by imports could reduce EU electricity demand by around one-quarter of today’s green electricity production in the EU, and around one-tenth of 2050 projected demand (McWilliams et al, 2025). The ensuing impact on EU energy prices would benefit industrial consumers, households and the public purse.

    The policy implications are two-fold.

    First, while subsidies to modernise and protect European heavy industry can be justified both by the green transition and by the need to retain potentially competitive industry in a context of possible Chinese overcapacity, public money should both be conditional on abatement efforts and go to less-energy-intensive downstream industries, rather than highly energy-intensive intermediate products. This requires a revamping of the EU Clean Industrial Deal, which does not presently discriminate between production stages that should remain in the EU in the long term and those that need not.

    Second, EU industrial policy must be linked to trade, investment and climate policies that embed low-cost energy intensive production in developing countries into EU value chains. The two pillars of EU climate policy discussed above – an EU-led carbon pricing and CBAM coalition, and an EU-led coalition to fund decarbonisation of power sectors in developing countries – are critical in this regard. In addition, Clean Trade and Investment Partnerships, as announced by the European Commission (Jütten, 2025), would need to be set up to both improve market access to the EU and transfer technology to those developing countries that have the potential to be reliable suppliers of green-energy-intensive intermediate products.

    Conceptually, the same reasoning could apply to the decarbonisation of other advanced countries. We have presented it for Europe because it is where the policy question arises.

    3.4 Pillar 4: Effective markets for carbon removal and nature restoration

    It is almost certain that the world will overshoot climate targets. This makes investment in negative emissions essential. Limiting global warming to below 1.5°C does not rely only on the containment of emissions, but also on large-scale deployment of carbon dioxide removal (CDR) technologies of all kinds. Some models project gross CDR volumes of 10 to 20 GtCO₂ per year by the second half of the twenty-first century, equivalent to one-quarter to one-half of today’s global emissions (Hoegh-Guldberg et al, 2018).

    Negative emissions can be achieved through natural sequestration, which relies on photosynthesis and ecosystem processes (eg afforestation, soil carbon, carbon stored in coastal and marine ecosystems), and technological solutions that extract CO₂ from the atmosphere, such as direct air capture and storage (DACS), which does not yet exist at scale.

    This pillar proposes two market innovations:

    1. A market mechanism for negative emissions: integrating clean-up certificates into com- pliance markets (starting with the EU emissions trading system, ETS) for carbon removals that are reliably permanent; and
    2. Credible markets for long-term nature-based carbon capture that also value the broader ecosystem services and co-benefits of nature restoration – not just the carbon.

    The goal is to prepare for a future in which net-negative emissions will be necessary in the second half of the century, to compensate for temperature overshoot and restore a safer climate trajectory.

    3.4.1 A market mechanism for negative emissions: clean-up certificates

    Following Edenhofer et al (2025), we propose a new market-based instrument in the form of clean-up certificates, designed to embed CDR into the EU ETS and make the financing of net-negative emissions feasible at scale. The certificates would offer firms a legal right to emit beyond their allowances today, in exchange for an obligation to remove the equivalent amount of CO₂ from the atmosphere in the future. This creates a form of carbon debt, explicitly linked to future removals.

    The EU ETS is approaching a structural turning point. Under current rules, the last allowances for energy and industrial sectors will be auctioned around 2039. Yet some residual emissions – particularly in hard-to-abate sectors such as cement – will remain too costly or infeasible to eliminate. Without a mechanism to offset these emissions, carbon prices could spike in the 2040s, undermining the predictability and effectiveness of the EU ETS. Moreover, firms are already making forward-looking investment decisions and are banking certificates. Introducing clean-up certificates now would enable regulated entities to anticipate future compliance costs, while generating demand and finance for removals today.

    The institutional redesign would involve two steps:

    1. Issuance of clean-up certificates: these certificates would authorise emissions today but create a carbon debt obligation to remove the equivalent CO₂ in the future.
    2. Creation of a European Carbon Central Bank (ECCB), which would oversee the issuance, verification and enforcement of carbon debt contracts. It would act as a regulatory and financial anchor, ensuring transparency, risk management and intertemporal consistency in carbon markets.

    Clean-up certificates introduce intertemporal flexibility into emissions trading – analo- gous to allowing not just banking but also borrowing. Firms can emit now and remove later if they expect future innovations to lower CDR costs. However, if they are pessimistic about future CDR potential, they will avoid incurring carbon debt and prefer immediate abatement.

    Time-inconsistency is obviously a major concern. Without safeguards, firms might bet on an excessively high pace of technological progress, become overindebted and end up defaulting on their carbon debt. To prevent such outcomes, Edenhofer et al (2025) propose to grant the European Commission the option of intervening in the market by limiting the amount of clean-up certificates. In addition, reducing the issuance of conventional allowances would increase overall ambition levels as a result of the overall cost reductions from introducing clean-up certificates. To insure against corporate bankruptcy, Edenhofer et al (2025) propose that firms issuing carbon debt post collateral in the form of security deposits at the ECCB. If the firm delivers the expected certified removals, the deposit is released. If it defaults, the ECCB retains the funds and uses them to procure equivalent removals elsewhere.

    The EU ETS should thus evolve from a pure mitigation instrument into a tool that manages the entire carbon cycle. Over the longer run, negative emissions from nature-based removals could be integrated, potentially as a separate category of clean-up certificate. The potential for such removals is particularly high in EMDEs and in low-income countries, which also host significant biodiversity. However, two conditions must be met: nature-based removals must be additional and permanent. Achieving this requires a fundamental redesign of nature markets, which we address next.

    3.4.2 A market for natural provision of negative emissions and nature restoration 

    Cantillon et al (2025) propose a novel design for nature markets to scale up carbon removals and nature restoration in the Global South. The aim would be to overcome the high transaction costs, low credibility and short-termism that characterise the current voluntary carbon markets. The proposed mechanism would address these design flaws through four innovations:

    1. Jurisdictional scale: projects would be defined at regional or provincial level rather than small-scale private projects. This scale would reduce leakage, improve monitoring and enhance additionality by aligning with regulatory boundaries. Jurisdictions would compete to attract capital.
    2. Equity-based instruments: instead of issuing credits, jurisdictions would sell shares in a portfolio of nature-based projects. These shares would entitle holders to receive ‘dividends’ in the form of measured carbon and biodiversity benefits (eg a quantity of avoided CO₂, increase in biodiversity). Dividends would be released prudently over time, with buffers to account for ecological risk. This would allow for permanent claims without assuming permanence in ecological systems.
    3. Primary market as a crowdfunding mechanism: jurisdictions would list projects with detailed descriptions and minimum funding thresholds. Investors would allocate capital across proposals. Prices would form endogenously, with projects that attract excess demand seeing rising share prices, while underfunded projects would be delisted. This competitive mechanism would incentivise jurisdictions to improve project quality and additionality.
    4. Public market governance: to ensure integrity and reduce fragmentation, the market infrastructure – project vetting, registry management – would be publicly governed. This structure should reduce certification costs and resolve conflicts of interest inherent in today’s privately run systems.

    The proposed share-based model would address the main shortcomings of credit markets by realigning incentives and embedding long-term commitment. Unlike credit buyers, shareholders would internalise ecological risk, fostering better stewardship and accounting for the impermanence of natural systems. Jurisdictional project scope and competitive pricing would enhance additionality and minimise leakage. By pricing a bundle of project attributes, the model would generate implicit values for biodiversity alongside carbon. Centralised governance and larger project scale would reduce transaction costs, while the secondary market would ensure liquidity. Overall, the approach should shift the market from transactional offsetting to long-term ecological investment.

    To scale up, the market would require reliable demand. Rather than relying solely on offsets, a boost to demand could come from mandating institutional investors to align the carbon footprints of their portfolios with the Paris-aligned trajectories (and to do the same with their biodiversity footprints when such standards are established) and authorise them to use nature shares (on top of any other asset reshuffling) to meet this goal. A major advantage of acting at the level of funds, rather than the underlying companies, is that it would not release these companies from any existing or upcoming obligations to decarbonise and reduce their biodiversity impacts.

    While the model is well suited for provision projects, conservation is harder to finance because it delivers no flow of carbon and no added biodiversity dividends. The benefits of conservation are in the preservation of stocks of carbon and biodiversity. Cantillon et al (2025) discuss different ways to address this: 1) conservation projects could be integrated into the mechanism, which would facilitate private funding but complicate the design, or 2) it would require a separate funding mechanism, as proposed for the Amazon (see Box 1). In addition, nature-harming subsidies should be eliminated.

    Continue Reading

  • JCP nominates chief justices of high courts – Pakistan

    JCP nominates chief justices of high courts – Pakistan

    The Judicial Commission of Pakistan (JCP) on Tuesday appointed the chief justices to the four high courts, a statement issued by the Supreme Court said.

    Per the statement, the JCP held four consecutive meetings to make a decision related to the appointments and, by a majority of its total membership in each meeting, opted to allow the acting chief justices to continue serving the top roles.

    Letters were subsequently issued to the prime minister’s principal secretary, informing the government about the nominations and requesting the forwarding of the same to the president for their appointment.

    The letters said that Justice Sarfraz Dogar was nominated as the new chief justice of the Islamabad High Court (IHC), Justice Rozi Khan Barrech as the chief justice for the Balochistan High Court (BHC), Justice Syed Muhammad Attique Shah for the Peshawar High Court, and Justice Junaid Ghaffar for the Sindh High Court (SHC).

    Pre­sident Asif Ali Zardari on Saturday had already formally decla­red Justice Dogar the “senior-most judge” of the IHC, following the issuance of a revised seniority list by the Ministry of Law and Justice.

    The development followed a ruling by the Supreme Court on June 19, upholding the constitutionality of transferring three judges from other provincial high courts and referring the matter of seniority determination to the president.

    On Friday, five IHC judges had challenged the Supreme Court’s decision to uphold the transfer of three judges — Justice Dogar from the LHC, Justice Khadim Hussain Soomro from the SHC, and Justice Muhammad Asif from the BHC.

    President Zardari had also declared that the status of the transfer of all three judges would be permanent.

    Continue Reading

  • German court suspends diesel scandal trial of former Volkswagen CEO Winterkorn

    German court suspends diesel scandal trial of former Volkswagen CEO Winterkorn

    A German court has suspended proceedings in the trial of former Volkswagen CEO Martin Winterkorn, who has been charged with fraud and market manipulation in connection with Volkswagen’s use of rigged software that let millions of diesel-engine cars che…

    FRANKFURT, Germany — A German court has suspended proceedings in the trial of former Volkswagen CEO Martin Winterkorn, who has been charged with fraud and market manipulation in connection with Volkswagen’s use of rigged software that let millions of diesel-engine cars cheat on emissions tests.

    The regional court in Braunschweig on Tuesday cited an unspecified health issue that meant Winterkorn, 78, was not in a condition to face trial.

    The court said in a statement that it had “provisionally terminated” the proceedings. It said the health issue represented a “temporary impediment” and would continue to be reviewed with the help of an expert so that proceedings could resume if Winterkorn recovers.

    Winterkorn went on trial in September, 2024 but the proceedings were suspended a few days later after Winterkorn had an accident.

    Germany’s code of criminal procedure allows for a court to provisionally terminate proceedings “if the absence of the indicted accused or some other personal impediment prevents the main hearing being held for a considerable time.”

    Prosecutors say Winterkorn knew about the illegal software well before the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency announced its discovery of the violation in September 2015. He resigned days later. He has said he learned about the practice only shortly before the announcement and earlier testified during civil proceedings that the allegations against him “are not correct.”

    In May, four former Volkswagen managers were convicted of fraud and two of them given prison sentences for their part in the manipulation of emissions controls.

    The former head of diesel development was sentenced to four and a half years in prison, and the head of drive train electronics to two years and seven months by the court in Braunschweig. Two others received suspended sentences of 15 months and 10 months.

    The company has paid more than $33 billion in fines and compensation to vehicle owners. Two VW managers received prison sentences in the U.S. The former head of the company’s Audi division, Rupert Stadler, was given a suspended sentence of 21 months and a fine of 1.1 million euros ($1.25 million). The sentence is still subject to appeal.

    .

    Continue Reading

  • Apple, Google, King, Supercell and more accused of ‘tricking kids’ with ‘fake age ratings’ – Mobilegamer.biz

    Apple, Google, King, Supercell and more accused of ‘tricking kids’ with ‘fake age ratings’ – Mobilegamer.biz

     

    UK campaign group The Good Law Project has accused Apple and Google of allowing ‘fake age ratings’ on the app stores – and says King, Supercell and many more have been deliberately providing them.

    The group has launched a new campaign accusing platform holders Apple and Google of deceiving players by allowing game-makers to display one age rating at the point of download, but hiding the ‘real’ age rating in their games’ service agreements.

    Game-makers specifically accused of the practice by the Good Law Project include King, Supercell, Century Games, Kooapps, Toca Boca and SayGames. But there are “thousands and thousands” more, says the group, which is also working with child safety NGO 5Rights to shed light on the issue.

    In particular, the campaign focuses on King’s Candy Crush Saga. The Good Law Project claims that King deceives players by showing a 4+ rating on the app stores, but a peek into the game’s service agreement actually requires players to be 13 or over to view the ads served in the game.

    The Good Law Project also namechecks Whiteout Survival, Clash of Clans, Pop Us!, Snake.io and Toca Boca World as supposedly having deceptive age ratings.

    “Candy Crush isn’t the only app playing this game,” says The Good Law Project. “Thousands and thousands of apps are declaring one age range across the top and hiding another in the terms and conditions.”

    “And it’s all to make money out of tricking kids,” the group continues. “Firms can’t build up profiles and dish out surveillance ads to children under 13 without explicit consent from their parents – it’s illegal. But the firms think they’ve covered their backs if the small print that nobody ever reads says users have to be “at least 13″, whatever it says at the top of the page.”

    “So young kids are playing apps that bombard them with ads aimed at much older kids. And app developers and app stores are complicit.”

    As a result of its findings, The Good Law Project filed an official complaint to the UK’s Competition and Markets Authority yesterday. The complaint claims that the behaviour is unlawful and in breach of UK consumer protection and data processing regulations.

    It also claims that Apple and Google have a “special responsibility to protect consumers’ interests” due to their “effective monopoly” on app stores. Apple and Google’s lack of oversight “constitute abuses of their respective dominant positions,” it says.

    Apple sent us the following statement in response to the Good Law Project’s claims: “We are committed to protecting user privacy and security and providing a safe experience for children. We do this by giving parents and developers important tools to help protect children on the App Store and across the apps they use.”

    “When parents or guardians create an Apple Account for a child under 13 years of age, tracking permissions are disabled by default – so apps can’t request to track them through App Tracking Transparency. These protections are based on the user’s age, not the app. We also require developers to provide clear age ratings consistent with App Store policies, and in instances where an app’s age rating does not match its content, we take immediate action to ensure the issue is corrected.”

    We also asked King, Google and Supercell for comment on this story, and will update this article with their remarks if or when they provide them.

    At the time of writing, over 6,800 people have added their name to The Good Law Project’s petition to force Google and Apple to make their app stores safer for children.

    Continue Reading

  • Climate change alters distribution of sea life

    The Korea Institute of Ocean Science and Technology (KIOST, President Hyi Seung Lee) established, through genetic connectivity analysis, that a northward shift in the habitat of Turbo sazae, from the southern coast to the eastern coast of Korea, is closely related to rising sea temperatures caused by climate change. The research findings were published in an international academic journal.*

    * Title of publication: Insights into the Genetic Connectivity and Climate-Driven Northward Range Expansion of Turbo sazae (Gastropoda: Turbinidae) Along the Eastern Coast of Korea. Hyun-sung Yang, Kyung-man Kwon & Hyun-soo Roh, KIOST; Young-Ghan Cho et al., NIFS. Animals, May 2, 2025.

     

    According to the National Comprehensive Investigation into Marine Ecosystems conducted by the Korea Marine Environment Management Corporation, T. sazae, which had primarily inhabited the southern coast of Korea, were found to have expanded their habitat 37 degrees north (near Uljin) as of 2018. This suggests that climate change-driven rises in sea temperatures are gradually expanding northward the inhabitable environment for sea life, which a research team at KIOST verified through genetic connectivity analysis.

    A team of researchers led by Dr. Hyun-sung Yang of the Tropical and Subtropical Research Center at KIOST and another research team led by Dr. Young-Ghan Cho of the Tidal Flat Research Institute at the National Institute of Fisheries Science collaborated on the study, which predicted the impact of barren ground* caused by climate change on marine benthic life and analyzed the physiological, ecological, and genetic characteristics of T. sazae accordingly. They found that the T. sazae found around Jeju Island and on the eastern coast were varieties with identical genetic characteristics.

    * The phenomenon in which kelp disappears from coastal rocky areas to be replaced by white calcareous algae, leaving the affected areas white. An element of marine desertification.

    In addition, a research team at the Jeju Bio Research Center at KIOST found the main cause of an observed decline in T. sazae population to be a decrease in immune function caused by rising sea temperatures. Previously, it had been speculated that urchin barrens changed the feeding patterns of T. sazae living around Jeju Island, causing the decline in their population, but the research findings* indicate that the changed feeding patterns do not impact T. sazae’s reproduction or physiology, and that the real cause is compromised immune function of the mollusk as a result of warmer waters.

    * Title of publication: Effect of Diet Changes in Benthic Ecosystems Owing to Climate Change on the Physiological Responses of Turbo sazae in Waters Around Jeju Island, Korea. Yong-kyun Ryu, Chulhong Oh, Hyun-sung Yang, KIOST. Marine Environmental Research, Feb. 6, 2025.

    The findings are scientific evidence that T. sazae larvae likely move northward along ocean currents such as the Tsushima Current to settle on the eastern coast, resulting in an expansion of their habitat. These findings are also a significant achievement in that they clarify some of the impacts of climate change on the distribution of sea life through a comprehensive analysis of the morphological features and genetic information of the T. sazae populations around Jeju Island and along the eastern coast.

    In particular, the fact that rising sea temperatures allow the northward expansion of T. sazae’s habitat is expected to be key information in understanding climate-adaptive mechanisms of sea life as well as in forming climate change response strategies.

    KIOST President Hyi Seung Lee explained, “Climate change-driven rises in sea temperatures are a core variable in the impact of climate change on marine ecosystems.” He went on to say, “KIOST will use its latest research findings to gain a scientific understanding of patterns of change in the distribution of sea life and continue the scientific mission to protect sea life.”


    Disclaimer: AAAS and EurekAlert! are not responsible for the accuracy of news releases posted to EurekAlert! by contributing institutions or for the use of any information through the EurekAlert system.

    Continue Reading

  • Italy has always been a country I’ve loved

    Italy has always been a country I’ve loved

    Ask Yuna Kim to share her memories of Italy when she was a competitive figure skater, and the answers come rushing in fondly.

    Kim, sometimes nicknamed the ‘Queen of Figure Skating‘, competed twice in Turin during her highly successful career. In 2007, she won the ISU Grand Prix Final, before taking home World Championships silver from the same city in 2010.

    In that latter competition, Kim – fresh off the back of being crowned Olympic champion a month earlier at Vancouver 2010 – struggled in her short program, finishing seventh, but rebounded with a stunning free skate (she won the segment) to leap to second overall.

    “I competed in Torino twice,” Kim recalled in a recent exclusive interview in Seoul, Republic of Korea. “In 2010, I participated in the World Championships just a one month after the Olympics, so I was really exhausted — but it was still a meaningful way to close out the Olympic season.

    “Italy has always been a country I’ve loved, even outside of competition. I’d love to visit again.”

    Perfect timing, then, that the Milano Cortina 2026 Olympic Winter Games are fewer than 200 days away.

    “Many athletes in various sports are aiming for good results at Milano Cortina 2026. I’m supporting them all the way, hoping they can prepare fully without any injuries to deliver their best performance on the Olympic stage,” Kim said.

    There’s no doubt figure skating will be top draw for Yuna Kim. But what other events does she hope to catch?

    “Aside from figure skating, I’m looking forward to outstanding performances in short track speed skating and snowboard halfpipe,” she said. “Regardless of results, I’m also looking forward to watching spectacular skiing events.”

    Continue Reading

  • Report: Knicks to conduct 2nd interview with Mike Brown for coaching job

    Report: Knicks to conduct 2nd interview with Mike Brown for coaching job

    Mike Brown is a two-time winner of the NBA Coach of the Year Award.

    • Download the NBA App
    • 2025 Free Agent Tracker

    NEW YORK (AP) — The New York Knicks will interview two-time NBA Coach of the Year Mike Brown for a second time as they seek Tom Thibodeau’s replacement, a person with knowledge of the details said Monday.

    Brown’s return this week will make him the first of the known candidates to get a second interview for the position that has been vacant for nearly a month.

    Other candidates could also be asked to return, the person told The Associated Press on condition of anonymity because details of the coaching search were to remain private. The Knicks have also talked with former Memphis coach Taylor Jenkins and assistants James Borrego of New Orleans and Micah Nori of Minnesota about the position.

    Brown’s second interview was first reported by the New York Post.

    Brown led the Sacramento Kings to the playoffs in 2023, their first appearance since 2006, and was voted coach of the year. He went 107-88 there in 2 1/2 seasons before he was fired during this past season.

    Brown also won the coaching award in 2009 with Cleveland and is 454-304 in his career.

    Thibodeau was fired June 3 despite leading the Knicks to the Eastern Conference finals for the first time in 25 years. Like Brown, he also won NBA Coach of the Year honors with two teams.

    Continue Reading

  • ARMing SCREAM with Observations to Expose Cloud Errors

    ARMing SCREAM with Observations to Expose Cloud Errors

    Editors’ Highlights are summaries of recent papers by AGU’s journal editors.
    Source: Journal of Geophysical Research: Atmospheres

    Clouds are a major source of uncertainty in atmospheric predictability and simulating them accurately remains a challenge for large-scale models. Bogenschutz et al. [2025] evaluate a new high-resolution model called the Simple Cloud-Resolving E3SM Atmosphere Model (SCREAM) developed by the United States Department of Energy (DOE), which is designed to better capture cloud and storm processes. The authors use a fast, small-scale version of the model and compare its output to modern real-world observations from the DOE’s Atmospheric Radiation Measurement (ARM) program.

    The model performed better at higher resolutions but still struggled with certain cloud types, especially mid-level “congestus” clouds that form between shallow and deep convection. SCREAM also tended to shift too abruptly from shallow clouds to intense storms, and its performance depended on how finely the vertical layers of the atmosphere were represented.

    These results help pinpoint key weaknesses in the model’s treatment of clouds and turbulence. The new library of ARM cases added in this work will help guide future improvements to SCREAM and support more accurate simulations of cloud processes.

    Citation: Bogenschutz, P. A., Zhang, Y., Zheng, X., Tian, Y., Zhang, M., Lin, L., et al. (2025). Exposing process-level biases in a global cloud permitting model with ARM observations. Journal of Geophysical Research: Atmospheres, 130, e2024JD043059. https://doi.org/10.1029/2024JD043059

    —Yun Qian, Editor, JGR: Atmospheres

    Text © 2025. The authors. CC BY-NC-ND 3.0
    Except where otherwise noted, images are subject to copyright. Any reuse without express permission from the copyright owner is prohibited.

    Continue Reading

  • Breakthrough study reveals killing power of CD4 T cells against cancer

    Breakthrough study reveals killing power of CD4 T cells against cancer

    In the fight against cancer, immunotherapy – which aims to boost the body’s natural defences against cancer – is experiencing remarkable growth. Most of these treatments are based on CD8 T lymphocytes, ”killer cells” able to eliminate diseased cells. A team from the University of Geneva (UNIGE) has explored an alternative approach involving CD4 T lymphocytes. Long considered mere auxiliary cells, their therapeutic potential has been considered of secondary importance. But the scientists have discovered that they also have strong killing capacity, while continuing to support other immune cells. Using cell engineering technologies, the team reprogrammed the cells to target a tumour marker found in many cancers, both in adults and children. These results, published in the journal Science Advances, offer hope for a faster therapeutic strategy that could benefit a greater number of patients.

    Traditionally considered as auxiliary cells, CD4 T cells produce molecules to support the action of other immune cells by facilitating their functions, migration or proliferation in the organism. Recent work by Camilla Jandus, Assistant Professor in the Department of Pathology and Immunology, in the Centre for Inflammation Research and in the Translational Research Centre in Onco-haematology at the UNIGE Faculty of Medicine, shows that they have been vastly underestimated.

    In collaboration with the CHUV-UNIL Oncology Department and the Lausanne Branch of the Ludwig Institute for Cancer Research, UNIGE scientists studied the molecular characteristics of CD4 T lymphocytes isolated from melanoma patients (a skin cancer). They identified that a unique subset of these cells bears a T cell receptor (TCR) capable of efficiently recognising an antigen specific to tumour cells: NY-ESO-1. This TCR was then isolated and artificially expressed in other CD4 T cells.

    We then evaluated the effectiveness of these engineered cells against cancer cells, both in vitro and in animal models. The results are impressive: they effectively target not only melanoma, but also lung, ovarian, sarcoma and brain cancers, while sparing healthy cells. This demonstrates that TCR-modified CD4 T cells can attack tumours directly, in addition to their auxiliary role”.


    Camilla Jandus, Assistant Professor in the Department of Pathology and Immunology, UNIGE Faculty of Medicine

    The major advantage of a widespread allele

    The HLA system is a set of genes responsible for immune recognition. Everyone inherits different versions of these genes, known as alleles. ”They code for cell surface proteins, HLA molecules, which enable the T cells to distinguish healthy cells from pathogen infected or malignant cells,” explains Camilla Jandus. ”The effectiveness of T cell-based therapies depends on whether the patient carries the specific HLA allele that presents the tumour antigen. The NY-ESO-1 antigen, recognised by our TCR, is presented by a widespread allele, found in about half the Caucasian population, compared to only 10 to 15% for other HLA alleles. This dramatically expands the pool of patients who could benefit, especially since the targeted antigen is expressed in many types of cancer”.

    Hope for adults and children with cancers

    Camilla Jandus’ team is currently preparing a clinical trial of TCR-engineered CD4-based cell therapy. The trial will include different types of cancer expressing NY-ESO-1. First, a HLA test will verify the presence of the appropriate HLA allele, and then tumours will be analysed to confirm expression of NY-ESO-1. The CD4 T cells will then be harvested, modified in the laboratory to express the TCR, multiplied and reinjected into the patient.

    But Camilla Jandus envisages a further step: the creation of a bank of ready-to-use TCR engineered immune cells from healthy donors, matched to avoid rejection, which would save precious time, especially in the case of aggressive cancers. This strategy could also pave the way for treatments for cancers that are currently incurable, particularly in children. The first in vitro tests on paediatric neuroblastomas are indeed promising.

    This research was supported by the ISREC Foundation, as part of the ISREC Tandem programme and the Fondazione San Salvatore.

    Continue Reading

  • Shorter days ahead? Earth’s rotation is speeding up, warn scientists

    Shorter days ahead? Earth’s rotation is speeding up, warn scientists

    We often think of time—like the 24-hour day—as something fixed and unchanging. But in reality, even Earth’s rotation isn’t constant. Scientists have now found that our planet is spinning faster than it used to, and that means days are getting just a tiny bit shorter.This might sound strange, but Earth’s rotation has always changed over long periods. Dinosaurs, for example, lived with 23-hour days. And in the Bronze Age, the average day was already about half a second shorter than today’s standard. Looking ahead, scientists predict that 200 million years from now, one Earth day will last about 25 hours.

    Why is the Earth spinning faster?

    Normally, a day lasts 24 hours, or 86,400 seconds. But that’s not completely accurate. Many things—like earthquakes, volcanic activity, ocean tides, and even underground changes—can make the planet spin slightly faster or slower. Even though the overall trend has been for Earth to slow down, something unusual has been happening since 2020.

    earth rotation1

    According to the International Earth Rotation and Reference Systems Service (IERS), based in Washington D.C., the Earth’s rotation has started to speed up. This has been happening steadily enough that experts now believe we may need to remove a leap second from our clocks in 2029—the first time this has ever happened.A recent report from timeanddate.com says that this trend will continue into 2025. Based on current data, the three shortest days of the year will be July 9, July 22, and August 5. The shortest of all, August 5, is expected to be about 1.51 milliseconds shorter than the usual 24 hours.

    What’s causing it?

    This unexpected speed-up has puzzled experts. Leonid Zotov, a rotation researcher at Moscow State University, told timeanddate.com, “Nobody expected this.” Zotov helped write a 2022 study trying to figure out the cause, but he says that so far, no model fully explains it.

    earth rotation2

    Most scientists believe the answer lies deep inside the Earth—possibly something happening in the core. Ocean and atmosphere changes don’t seem to account for the speed increase.While this spinning trend might continue for now, it’s not a sign that we’re heading back to dinosaur-era days. Earth’s long-term natural tendency is still to slow down over time. Things like melting ice at the poles and surface changes can also affect this.So, while we might “lose” a leap second soon, Earth isn’t going off track—just reminding us that even time isn’t perfectly steady.


    Continue Reading