Blog

  • New Species of Permian Herbivorous Tetrapod Identified in China

    New Species of Permian Herbivorous Tetrapod Identified in China

    Paleontologists have identified a new genus and species of mid-sized pareiasaur from two fossilized specimes found in China in 2018.

    An artist’s reconstruction of Yinshanosaurus angustus. Image credit: X.-C. Guo, Institute of Vertebrate Paleontology and Paleoanthropology.

    Named Yinshanosaurus angustus, the newly-identified species roamed Earth during the latest Permian period, between 259 and 254 million years ago.

    The ancient beast was a member of Pareiasauria, a specialized group of herbivorous tetrapods that existed throughout the supercontinent Pangea during the Middle-Late Permian.

    “Pareiasauria are a bizarre herbivorous clade of tetrapods that existed in the Guadalupian and Lopingian and were victims of both the Late Capitanian and the end-Permian mass extinction events,” said Dr. Jian Yi and Jun Liu from the Institute of Vertebrate Paleontology and Paleoanthropology at the Chinese Academy of Sciences, the University of Chinese Academy of Sciences, and Chongqing Institute of Paleontology.

    “Pareiasauria has a worldwide distribution, with fossils discovered in Africa, Europe, Asia and South America.”

    “Pareiasaurs were common primary consumers in several terrestrial tetrapod faunas, including the Late Permian fauna of northern China.”

    “Since the 1960s, eight Chinese pareiasaur species have been described.”

    Two specimens — a nearly complete skull and an articulated partial postcranial skeleton with a nearly complete skull — were unearthed in China in 2018.

    “The first specimen was excavated form the dark purple siltstone in the lower part of the Sunjiagou Formation, near Zhangjiagetuo village, Baode county, Xinzhou city, Shanxi,” the paleontologists said.

    “The second specimen was excavated from purplish silty mudstone in the upper part of Member I of the Naobaogou Formation, near Qiandian village, Shiguai district of Baotou City, Nei Mongol.”

    According to the authors, Yinshanosaurus angustus had the narrowest skull of all pareiasaurs, with skull length more than twice the skull width at the lateral edges of the cheeks.

    “The skeleton of Yinshanosaurus angustus provides the complete cranial and articulated postcranial details of Chinese pareiasaurs for the first time,” they said.

    Their paper was published this month in the journal Papers in Palaeontology.

    _____

    Jian Yi & Jun Liu. 2025. The tetrapod fauna of the upper Permian Naobaogou Formation of China: a new mid-sized pareiasaur Yinshanosaurus angustus and its implications for the phylogenetic relationships of pareiasaurs. Papers in Palaeontology 11 (3): e70020; doi: 10.1002/spp2.70020

    Continue Reading

  • UK food prices push up shop price inflation for first time in nearly a year – Reuters

    1. UK food prices push up shop price inflation for first time in nearly a year  Reuters
    2. UK BRC Shop Price Index for June 2025: +0.4% y/y (prior –0.1%)  Forexlive | Forex News, Technical Analysis & Trading Tools
    3. Grocery footfall, mobile overtakes TV, alcohol ads: 5 interesting stats to start your week  Marketing Week
    4. Butter at 18%? Food Inflation Shock Explained  MSN
    5. Shop prices return to inflation for first time in almost a year  Yahoo

    Continue Reading

  • A Modern Lake in an Ancient Crater

    A Modern Lake in an Ancient Crater

    A false-color version of the image shows the snow-covered vegetation as greenish-blue. Snow and ice appear blue, including the ice that covers the ring-shaped lake centered in the image.

    Terrain with some varied texture appears gray and white across most of the scene. A ring-shaped lake is centered in the image and appears white.
    A false-color version of the image shows the snow-covered vegetation as greenish-blue. Snow and ice appear blue, including the ice that covers the ring-shaped lake centered in the image.

    Impact craters exist on every continent on Earth. While many have eroded away or been buried by geologic activity, some remain visible from the ground and from above. This week, we revisit stories featuring some of our most captivating satellite images of impact sites around the planet. The images and text on this page were originally published on February 4, 2022.

    In southeastern Québec lies one of the world’s largest impact craters. Manicouagan Crater was formed 214 million years ago, near the end of the Triassic Period, when an asteroid 5 kilometers (3 miles) wide struck what is now Canada. Today, the remnants of the crater are made visible by water and, sometimes, ice.

    These images of Manicouagan Lake were acquired by the MODIS (Moderate Resolution Imaging Spectroradiometer) on NASA’s Terra satellite on January 20, 2022. A natural-color image of the frozen lake is compared with a false-color image. In the false-color image, which uses MODIS bands 7-2-1, snow or ice appears electric blue and vegetation appears green. A blanket of snow covering the surrounding vegetation gives it a greenish-blue color.

    Sometimes called the “Eye of Québec,” the 1,940-square-kilometer (750-square-mile) ring-shaped lake is readily identifiable from space. The unique shape makes it a popular feature in satellite imagery and a favorite subject of astronaut photography. Despite the crater’s ancient age, the events that gave rise to the lake coincided with the dawn of the Space Age.

    In the 1960s, Hydro-Québec constructed the Daniel-Johnson Dam—the largest multiple arch-and-buttress concrete dam in the world—on the Manicouagan River. Prior to the dam’s completion in 1968, two separate crescent-shaped lakes flanked the sides of the impact crater: Manicouagan Lake on the east and Mouchalagane (Mushalagan) Lake on the west. As the water levels rose over the next few years, the previously isolated water bodies joined to form the Manicouagan Reservoir, which finished filling in 1977.

    Today, the reservoir reaches a depth of roughly 350 meters (1,150 feet) and holds 140 cubic kilometers (34 cubic miles) of water, making it one of the largest freshwater reservoirs in the world. The outflow from the dam drains south into the Manicouagan River, which empties into the St. Lawrence River.

    After the river was impounded, water rising behind the dam encircled the higher land in the center of the impact crater; René-Levasseur Island was formed. The highest point on the island is Mount Babel, which rises 600 meters (1,970 feet) above the lake level on its northern end.

    Mount Babel is the crater’s central peak, which formed in the aftermath of the impact when shattered rock and debris were uplifted. Geologists estimate that the crater was initially about 100 kilometers (60 miles) wide. It has since been heavily eroded and scoured by ice sheets and today measures 72 kilometers (45 miles) in diameter.

    NASA Earth Observatory images by Lauren Dauphin, using MODIS data from NASA EOSDIS LANCE and GIBS/Worldview. Story by Sara E. Pratt.

    Continue Reading

  • U.S. approves $510 million sale of bomb guidance kits to Israel

    U.S. approves $510 million sale of bomb guidance kits to Israel

    U.S. President Donald Trump. File
    | Photo Credit: Reuters

    The United States on Monday (June 30, 2025) announced the approval of a $510 million sale to Israel of bomb guidance kits and related support, after Israel expended significant munitions in its recent conflict with Iran.

    “The proposed sale will enhance Israel’s capability to meet current and future threats by improving its ability to defend Israel’s borders, vital infrastructure, and population centres,” the U.S. Defence Security Cooperation Agency (DSCA) said in a statement.

    “The United States is committed to the security of Israel, and it is vital to US national interests to assist Israel to develop and maintain a strong and ready self-defense capability,” it added.

    The State Department approved the possible sale and the DSCA has provided the required notification to the US Congress, which still needs to sign off on the transaction.

    Israel launched an unprecedented air campaign on June 13 targeting Iranian nuclear sites, scientists and top military brass in a bid to end the country’s nuclear program, which Tehran says is for civilian purposes but Washington and other powers insist is aimed at acquiring atomic weapons.

    Trump had spent weeks pursuing a diplomatic path to replace the nuclear deal with Tehran that he tore up in 2018 during his first term, but he ultimately decided to take military action, ordering US strikes on Iranian nuclear sites.

    A ceasefire brought the war to a halt last week, but Israeli Prime Minister Benjamin Netanyahu has vowed to prevent Tehran from ever rebuilding its nuclear facilities, raising the prospect of a future conflict.

    Continue Reading

  • Phiphen Games Releases Debut Title Ruffy and the Riverside – ACCESS Newswire

    1. Phiphen Games Releases Debut Title Ruffy and the Riverside  ACCESS Newswire
    2. ‘Ruffy and the Riverside’ Feels Like Pure Joy and Has All the Makings To Be a New Age Classic (Review)  VICE
    3. Mini Review: Ruffy and the Riverside (PS5) – A Cute Platformer with Missed Potential  Push Square
    4. Banjo-Kazooie and Paper Mario mix together in this delightful puzzle platformer that has me swapping textures to solve puzzles by changing the world  MSN
    5. Ruffy and the Riverside Review  TheSixthAxis

    Continue Reading

  • Parents face barriers to vaccinating children, says report

    Parents face barriers to vaccinating children, says report

    Getty Images A young child wearing a green top has her sleeve rolled up and is ready to get a vaccine from a doctor (unpictured) whose arms and hands are in view, who is holding a vaccineGetty Images

    Parents are being prevented from vaccinating their children because of obstacles such as difficulty booking appointments and a lack of reminders on what jabs are needed and when, a report suggests.

    Child health experts say “practical or logistical reasons” are discouraging families more often than fears over the vaccines.

    Vaccine uptake in the UK has fallen over the last decade, leading to outbreaks of measles and whooping cough.

    UK health officials say they are committed to working with the NHS to improve vaccine uptake among children.

    ‘Easier access’

    Since 2022, no childhood vaccine in the UK has met the World Health Organisation target of 95% of children vaccinated, which ensures protection of vulnerable people. As a result, measles and other preventable diseases have made a comeback.

    A commission of experts from the Royal College of Paediatrics and Child Health (RCPCH) spent a year looking at why.

    Dr Helen Stewart, officer for health improvement at RCPCH, said the steady decline in vaccination rates in a wealthy country like the UK was “extremely concerning”.

    But she said vaccine hesitancy, when parents waver over getting their children vaccinated, “is only part of a very complex picture”.

    “The reality is that there are many who simply need better support and easier access to appointments,” Dr Stewart said.

    Although confidence in vaccines is still relatively high, the report found barriers to accessing jabs are why many families don’t protect their children.

    Some of the most common barriers include:

    • difficulties getting through to book appointments at GP surgeries
    • difficulties getting time off work for appointments
    • limited transport options or no parking at GP surgeries
    • not seeing the same GP each time so lack of trust
    • not being able to speak to a GP or nurse to ask about the vaccines
    • lack of reminders for jabs being sent out from GP
    • not enough clear information about what jabs their child needs and when

    “One of the findings of this new report is that parents have no easy way to check their child’s vaccination status,” says children’s emergency medicine specialist, Dr Stewart.

    “When I ask if the child is up to date with their vaccinations, the most common response is ‘I think so’.”

    Poorer families, some ethnic minority groups and migrant communities are much less likely to be vaccinated, and these inequalities have become more obvious since the pandemic, the report says.

    It also notes an absence of health visitors often means parents have no one they feel comfortable discussing vaccines openly with.

    Digital red book

    The report recommends using NHS apps to improve the experience of booking jabs, investing and expanding vaccination services, and funding health visitors to deliver some of them.

    It also calls on the development of the ‘digital red book’ to be finalised so parents can keep track of their children’s vaccinations.

    The NHS website lists the full schedule of vaccinations for children, from babies, up to the age of 15.

    Dr Julie Yates, deputy director for immunisation programmes at UK Health Security Agency, said plans were in place to improve childhood vaccine uptake by ensuring more flexible appointment booking systems, making vaccines more widely available across different locations, and making access easier in all communities.

    “Despite the challenges, it is also important to note that parents have high confidence in vaccinations with almost 90% agreeing vaccines are effective,” Dr Yates said.

    Alison Morton, chief executive of the Institute for Health Visitors, said the report presented “a compelling case” to ensure babies and children are protected against serious diseases which can cause so much unnecessary harm.

    Helen Bedford, professor of children’s health at University College London, said improvements needed investment in staff and infrastructure.

    “Our children have the right to be protected from preventable diseases which can cause illness, disability or even death,” she said, adding that a fall in children getting their vaccines had resulted in the deaths of 11 young babies from whooping cough last year. 

    Falling vaccinations among children isn’t just an issue in the UK, in 2023 there were nearly 16 million children who had not had any vaccinations, most of them in south Asia and sub-Saharan Africa.

    Continue Reading

  • End of the line for King Charles' royal train – Reuters

    1. End of the line for King Charles’ royal train  Reuters
    2. Royal Train To Be Decommissioned Following Review Reveal Royal Accounts  Banbury FM
    3. Britain’s royal train to be retired  trains.com
    4. Royal train to end 156 years of service as King Charles III seeks to economize  WETM
    5. End of the line for Britain’s royal train  Citizen Tribune

    Continue Reading

  • Surging Nonbank Lending Triggers Risks Across Financial Markets

    Surging Nonbank Lending Triggers Risks Across Financial Markets

    Last week, news came that Meta was moving toward obtaining $29 billion from private equity firms to help finance artificial intelligence (AI) data centers, according to the Financial Times.

    And as PYMNTS reported last month, Apollo Global Management is working with five banks, including JPMorgan Chase & Co. and Goldman Sachs Group, to trade private credit.

    As the lines blur in financial services, and traditional banking players link with nonbanks to expand credit, so too is there a blurring of the nomenclature of those efforts, referred to variously as shadow banking or nonbank financial intermediation.

    Data found in this Monday (June 30) post by the St. Louis Federal Reserve underscore the magnitude of exposure. As measured at the end of the first quarter of 2025, U.S. banks held $1.14 trillion in loans outstanding to the nonbank financial sector.

    “This interconnectedness between banks and nonbanks adds an extra layer of intermediation, as banks lend to mortgage companies, insurance companies, investment funds (such as mutual funds, money market funds, hedge funds and private capital funds), pension funds, broker-dealers, securitization vehicles and other financial entities, which then lend directly to end users in the economy,” noted the Fed. The growth rate of non-depository financial institutional lending has grown by 26% on average each year since 2012.

    Getting a bit more granular, the Financial Stability Board estimated late last year that the aggregate FinTech lending across seven jurisdictions came in at $38.5 billion.

    As the FSB elaborated, “FinTech lending platforms can act as auxiliaries or intermediaries. As auxiliaries, they can be in the form of a ‘marketplace platform,’ which is an online market that allows lenders to trade directly with borrowers (peer-to-peer lending and crowdfunding platforms). Fintech lending platforms can act as intermediaries when they use their balance sheets to originate the lending.”

    Loans to mortgage and private credit intermediaries each represent 23% of loans outstanding, and loans to business intermediaries and consumer intermediaries represent 21% and 9%, respectively, estimated the Fed.

    Risks of ‘Runnable’ Activity

    In separate data and analysis as of last week, according to a report by the Congressional Research Service, “banks are increasingly lending to NBFIs (nonbank financial institutions) and, at the same time, reducing their lending to commercial and industrial borrowers.”

    “Increased lending from banks to NBFIs could expose banks to counterparty credit risk and spillover effects during a financial crisis…” the report added. “The size and growth of NBFI suggest that significant amount of financing is being intermediated and held outside of the banking sector. In contrast to the traditional banking model, where banks normally manage risks (e.g., credit, market, liquidity, and operational risks) on their balance sheets, the market-based NBFI financing model shifts risks toward capital markets investors and intermediaries.”

    As for the risks, the CRS cautioned that the “vulnerabilities affecting financial stability are present in capital markets NBFI, including in certain money-like instruments that face potential ‘runs,’ leverage levels, interconnectedness between nonbanks and banks, data and transparency issues, liquidity mismatch at certain open-end funds, and concentration risk at market intermediaries.”

    There’s a knock-on effect here, as some financial institutions are grappling with shadow banking stalwarts as competitors, which in turn has shifted activities away from core deposits toward long-term securities and other holdings. In this paper from economists at the Fed and at the University of Houston, there’s the contention that in doing so, net interest income margins are pressured.

    Continue Reading

  • Record 256,000 Afghan Migrants Return from Iran as IOM Warns of Dire Funding Shortfall – ReliefWeb

    1. Record 256,000 Afghan Migrants Return from Iran as IOM Warns of Dire Funding Shortfall  ReliefWeb
    2. Over 230,000 Afghans left Iran in June ahead of deadline  Dawn
    3. Nowhere to run: The Afghan refugees caught in Israel’s war on Iran  Al Jazeera
    4. No Safe Return: The Case Against Deporting Afghan Refugees  The Diplomat – Asia-Pacific Current Affairs Magazine
    5. TAWDIKHABARI – Deportation of Afghan Refugees from Iran, Pakistan Discussed  TOLOnews

    Continue Reading

  • Households’ subjective expectations: Disagreement, common drivers, and reaction to aggregate shocks

    Household expectations are usually thought to play a central role in the transmission of macroeconomic policy. Yet we still know too little about how households perceive and interpret the complex relationships and feedback between relevant economic variables that are at the core of general equilibrium. In a recent project (Ferreira and Pica 2025), we use new euro area household level survey data to show that households interpret contractionary demand and supply shocks as inflationary, contrary to conventional macroeconomic models. Our paper contributes to a recent literature investigating households’ mental models about economic relationships (e.g. André et al. 2022, Piccolo et al. 2025).

    The misalignment we uncover emerges consistently across time, countries, demographic groups, and levels of financial literacy. Although disagreement is pervasive, there is a clear structure in household expectations: two common factors explain a large share of the variation in beliefs within and across individual households in different countries.

    These patterns challenge standard assumptions in macroeconomic models and raise important questions about the communication and effectiveness of monetary policy. When central banks raise interest rates, they do so partly to influence expectations. However, if households’ understanding of and attention to transmission mechanisms differ from those assumed in the models that justify such rate changes – and if the households act on these beliefs – the impact of a policy may diverge from its intended effect. The links between expectations, real outcomes, and monetary policy has been explored in other Vox columns (e.g. Gorodnichenko et al. 2019, 2021, Weber et al. 2021).

    The effect of aggregate demand and supply shocks on expectations

    A natural way to explore the mental models that households entertain about economic dynamics is to evaluate the impact that exogenous shifts in demand and supply curves have on beliefs. Under rational expectations, these shifts should affect expectations about prices and quantities in a specific direction. We study how households in six major euro area economies – Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, and Spain – respond to aggregate shocks using the ECB’s high-frequency Consumer Expectations Survey. This monthly panel captures detailed, household-level expectations about inflation, unemployment, interest rates, the general economic outlook, and other variables.

    Our first key finding is that contractionary monetary policy shocks raise inflation expectations. Specifically, following an ECB rate increase, households expect not only slower economic growth and higher unemployment, but also higher inflation over the next 12 months (Figure 1). This response is surprising. In textbook New Keynesian models, tighter monetary policy reduces demand and dampens inflation. Households’ expectations in our data move in the opposite direction and do so persistently. This result is in line with André et al. (2022) and Piccolo et al. (2025). One of our contributions to this literature is to validate these results internally across different identification strategies – including an event-study around ECB meetings – using alternative data sources going back to 2000. In addition, we show a surprising robustness across countries and demographic groups.

    Figure 1 Impulse responses of household expectations to a contractionary monetary policy shock

    Note: Impulse response functions of household expectations following a contractionary monetary surprise that raises the short rate by 25 basis points on impact. These responses are estimated using the panel local projections with Newey-West standard errors clustered at the monthly level. The 95% confidence intervals are shown in light blue; the 68% confidence intervals in dark blue. The estimation sample spans April 2020 to January 2024 for all variables except interest rate expectations, which are available from September 2020 onward.

    Turning to oil shocks, household-level responses align closely with the expected effects of a stagflationary shock: a rise in the real oil price leads to higher expected inflation while lowering expected economic growth (Figure 2).

    We therefore conclude that households consistently interpret contractionary supply and demand shocks as inflationary.

    Figure 2 Impulse responses of household expectations to a contractionary oil shock

    Notes: Impulse response functions of household expectations following a contractionary oil shock that raises the real oil price by 10% on impact. These responses are estimated using panel local projections with Newey-West standard errors clustered at the monthly level. The 95% confidence intervals are shown in light blue; the 68% confidence intervals in dark blue. The estimation sample spans April 2020 to June 2024 for all variables except interest rate expectations, which are available from September 2020 onward.

    Common drivers of beliefs

    Despite significant and persistent disagreement, household expectations move together in systematic ways. We uncover two latent drivers (principal components) that explain around 40% of the variation in expectations across households and countries.

    The first component reflects a broad perception that inflation is bad for the economy due, for example, to its origin on supply side shocks or to its erosion of disposable real incomes (Kamdar and Ray 2024, Binetti et al. 2024). Households that expect higher inflation also anticipate slower growth and weaker labour markets. This ‘inflation pessimism’ dominates the structure of expectations and suggests a mental model wherein price increases are interpreted as a sign of worsening real conditions.

    The second component captures concerns about interest rates and unemployment. Households that expect higher interest rates also expect weaker economic outcomes, suggesting that they associate rate hikes with cost increases and labour market deterioration, rather than with disinflationary effects.

    Strikingly, these latent drivers are not systematically linked to observable characteristics like age, education, housing tenure, or financial literacy. Nor are they specific to any one country. This points to a shared cognitive framework – a simplified but common view of the business cycle – that shapes how households interpret macroeconomic developments.

    Building on this, we estimate a two-factor structure for the cross-section of all expectations. The structure is general enough to capture individual time-invariant biases and disturbances, and can be mapped onto most equilibrium models with a generalised expectation formation process. The first factor, which explains the bulk of the time-series variation, tracks inflation-related sentiment potentially emerging from attention to media outlets, including the supply bottlenecks of 2021, the energy crisis, and ECB rate hikes from mid-2022 onward. The second factor correlates closely with unemployment dynamics, suggesting that demand-side perceptions are linked primarily to real activity (Figure 3).

    Figure 3 Evolution of identified factors over the sample period

    Note: Figure plots factors identified through sign restrictions on household expectations data; sample covers the period from September 2020 to December 2024. The two thick lines represent the optimal uncorrelated factors, identified using a standard Euclidean metric. The thinner lines show the 10th, 25th, 50th, 75th, and 90th percentiles of the distribution of distances for alternative valid models (i.e. rotations). Blue lines correspond to the first factor, identified by loadings that capture opposite correlations between expected economic growth and expected inflation. Red lines correspond to the second factor, identified based on demand-type signs on expected economic growth and expected inflation. Vertical solid lines mark key events: (1) disruptions in the Suez and Panama Canals (May 2021), (2) the Russian invasion of Ukraine (February 2022), and (3) the ECB’s first post-pandemic interest rate hike (July 2022).

    Conclusions and implications for policy

    Understanding how households interpret macroeconomic policy is vital for the effectiveness of central bank action. Our study shows that households often react in ways that contradict the standard theoretical playbook. This misalignment is systematic and rooted in a shared structure of beliefs, not idiosyncratic noise.

    These findings have important implications. If households believe that contractionary monetary policy fuels rather than curbs inflation, then standard policy levers may be less effective than models suggest. Communication strategies that rely on rational expectations may fall flat if the public’s mental model of the economy diverges fundamentally from that of policymakers.

    Moreover, if inflation expectations are not anchored by policy signals but are instead shaped by perceived cost pressures, there is a risk of self-fulfilling inflation dynamics. Policymakers may inadvertently reinforce inflation fears if rate hikes are seen as signs of economic trouble rather than tools to stabilise prices.

    Our evidence suggests that households interpret shocks through a lens shaped by recent crises – such as the energy shock following Russia’s invasion of Ukraine – and by deep-rooted concerns about real purchasing power. Addressing these perceptions may require more than technical briefings or forecasts. Clear, relatable narratives about how policy affects inflation and the broader economy are essential.

    References

    Andre, P, C Pizzinelli, C Roth and J Wohlfart (2022), “Subjective Models of the Macroeconomy: Evidence from Experts and Representative Samples”, Review of Economic Studies 86(6): 2958–91.

    Binetti, A, F Nuzzi and S Stantcheva (2024), “People’s understanding of inflation”, Journal of Monetary Economics 148, 103652.

    Coibion, O, Y Gorodnichenko and M Weber (2022), “Monetary Policy Communications and Their Effects on Household Inflation Expectations”, Journal of Political Economy 130(6): 1537–84.

    Ferreira, C and S Pica (2005), “Households’ Subjective Expectations: Disagreement, Common Drivers, and Reaction to Monetary Policy”, Banco de Espana Working Paper No. 2445.

    Gorodnichenko, Y, M Weber and O Coibion (2019), “Monetary policy communications and their effects on household inflation expectations”, VoxEU.org, 22 February.

    Gorodnichenko, Y, M Weber and O Coibion (2021), “How inflation expectations affect households’ spending decisions”, VoxEU.org, 19 March.

    Kamdar, R and W Ray (2024), “Attention-Driven Sentiment and the Business Cycle”, University of Oxford Working Paper.

    Piccolo, J, A Russo, E Granziera and E Castelnuovo (2025), “Households’ Macroeconomic Beliefs: The Role of Education”, Marco Fanno Working Paper 316, Universita Degli Studi di Padova.

    Weber, M, G Kenny, D Georgarakos, Y Gorodnichenko and O Coibion (2021), “The effect of macroeconomic uncertainty on household spending”, VoxEU.org, 31 July.

    Continue Reading