Category: 3. Business

  • Oil edges down on expectations of more OPEC+ supply, tariff fears – Reuters

    1. Oil edges down on expectations of more OPEC+ supply, tariff fears  Reuters
    2. Opec+ poised to raise output in August  Dawn
    3. Oil edges down on easing Middle East risks but gains for a second month  Reuters
    4. Oil prices steady on easing Middle East risks  Business Recorder
    5. Missed The Last Oil Rally? This Pullback Could Be Your Second Chance  FXEmpire

    Continue Reading

  • South Korea exports rebound on tech boost but US, China shipments extend losses – Reuters

    1. South Korea exports rebound on tech boost but US, China shipments extend losses  Reuters
    2. South Korea Trade Surplus Largest in A Year  TradingView
    3. Tariffs, global slump cloud Korea’s Q3 export outlook  theinvestor.co.kr
    4. South Korea’s Exports Rebound Despite Tariff Woes  WSJ
    5. South Korea’s Fiscal Gambit: Can Lee’s Stimulus and US Trade Talks Revive Key Sectors?  AInvest

    Continue Reading

  • Japan factory activity grows for first time in 13 months, PMI shows – Reuters

    1. Japan factory activity grows for first time in 13 months, PMI shows  Reuters
    2. Japan: Indices of Industrial Production for May, 2025 (Preliminary Report)  Forex Factory
    3. Navigating Japan’s Manufacturing Crossroads: Tariffs, Yen, and Strategic Opportunities  AInvest
    4. JGB Futures Fall as Investors Digest Japanese Economic Data  MSN
    5. Japan’s industrial output grows by 0.5% in May  breakingthenews.net

    Continue Reading

  • Japan business mood improves despite tariff risks, BOJ tankan shows – Reuters

    1. Japan business mood improves despite tariff risks, BOJ tankan shows  Reuters
    2. Japan big makers’ confidence improves to 13 in June from 12: BOJ  毎日新聞
    3. Japan’s Large Manufacturing Index rises to 13.0 in the second quarter (Q2) of 2025 – Tankan survey  FXStreet
    4. BOJ Tankan survey, Dalai Lama speech, BRICS summit  Nikkei Asia
    5. The Bank of Japan Tankan report is due soon, here are the Reuters results as a preview  Forexlive | Forex News, Technical Analysis & Trading Tools

    Continue Reading

  • Tuesday’s big stock stories: What’s likely to move the market in the next trading session – CNBC

    Tuesday’s big stock stories: What’s likely to move the market in the next trading session – CNBC

    1. Tuesday’s big stock stories: What’s likely to move the market in the next trading session  CNBC
    2. Morning News Wrap-Up: Monday’s Biggest Stock Market Stories!  TipRanks
    3. Friday’s big stock stories: What’s likely to move the market in the next trading session  CNBC
    4. Morning News Wrap-Up: Friday’s Biggest Stock Market Stories!  The Globe and Mail
    5. Morning News Wrap-Up: Wednesday’s Biggest Stock Market Stories!  TipRanks

    Continue Reading

  • Robbins LLP Informs Investors of the

    Robbins LLP Informs Investors of the

    SAN DIEGO, June 30, 2025 (GLOBE NEWSWIRE) — Robbins LLP informs stockholders that a class action was filed on behalf of investors who purchased or otherwise acquired Sarepta Therapeutics, Inc. (NASDAQ: SRPT) securities between June 22, 2023 and June 24, 2025. Sarepta is a commercial-stage biopharmaceutical company that focuses on RNA and gene therapies for the treatment of rare diseases. During the class period, Sarepta was engaged in the development of therapies to treat Duchenne muscular dystrophy (“Duchenne”), including ELEVIDYS. ELEVIDYS is a prescription gene therapy intended for a limited category of people with Duchenne.

    For more information, submit a form, email attorney Aaron Dumas, Jr., or give us a call at (800) 350-6003.

    The Allegations: Robbins LLP is Investigating Allegations that Sarepta Therapeutics, Inc. (SRPT) Mislead Investors Regarding the Safety its ELEVIDYS Drug

    According to the complaint, during the class period, defendants failed to disclose that: (i) ELEVIDYS posed significant safety risks to patients; (ii) ELEVIDYS trial regimes and protocols failed to detect severe side effects; and (iii) the severity of adverse events from ELEVIDYS treatment would cause the Company to halt recruitment and dosing in ELEVIDYS trials, attract regulatory scrutiny, and create greater risk around the therapy’s present and expanded approvals.

    Plaintiff alleges that on March 18, 2025, Sarepta issued a safety update on ELEVIDYS announcing that a patient had died following treatment with ELEVIDYS. On this news, Sarepta’s stock price fell $27.81 per share, or 27.44%, to close at $73.54 per share on March 18, 2025. Then, on June 15, 2025, Sarepta disclosed a second patient had died of acute liver failure following treatment with ELEVIDYS. The Company announced it was suspending shipments of ELEVIDYS for non-ambulatory patients while Sarepta took time to evaluate trial regimens and discussed findings with regulatory authorities. Sarepta also revealed that it was pausing dosing in one of its ELEVIDYS clinical studies. On this news, Sarepta’s stock price fell $15.24 per share, or 42.12%, to close at $20.91 per share on June 15, 2025.

    Finally, on June 24, 2025, the FDA announced it was investigating the risk of acute liver failure with serious outcomes following treatment with ELEVIDYS. On this nes, Sarepta’s stock price fell $1.52 per share, or 8.01%, to close at $17.46 per share on June 25, 2025.

    What Now: You may be eligible to participate in the class action against Sarepta Therapeutics, Inc. Shareholders who want to serve as lead plaintiff for the class must file a motion for lead plaintiff by August 25, 2025. The lead plaintiff is a representative party who acts on behalf of other class members in directing the litigation. You do not have to participate in the case to be eligible for a recovery. If you choose to take no action, you can remain an absent class member. For more information, click here.

    All representation is on a contingency fee basis. Shareholders pay no fees or expenses.  

    About Robbins LLP: A recognized leader in shareholder rights litigation, the attorneys and staff of Robbins LLP have been dedicated to helping shareholders recover losses, improve corporate governance structures, and hold company executives accountable for their wrongdoing since 2002.

    To be notified if a class action against Sarepta Therapeutics, Inc. settles or to receive free alerts when corporate executives engage in wrongdoing, sign up for Stock Watch today.

    Attorney Advertising. Past results do not guarantee a similar outcome.

    Continue Reading

  • UK food prices push up shop price inflation for first time in nearly a year – Reuters

    1. UK food prices push up shop price inflation for first time in nearly a year  Reuters
    2. UK BRC Shop Price Index for June 2025: +0.4% y/y (prior –0.1%)  Forexlive | Forex News, Technical Analysis & Trading Tools
    3. Grocery footfall, mobile overtakes TV, alcohol ads: 5 interesting stats to start your week  Marketing Week
    4. Butter at 18%? Food Inflation Shock Explained  MSN
    5. Shop prices return to inflation for first time in almost a year  Yahoo

    Continue Reading

  • Surging Nonbank Lending Triggers Risks Across Financial Markets

    Surging Nonbank Lending Triggers Risks Across Financial Markets

    Last week, news came that Meta was moving toward obtaining $29 billion from private equity firms to help finance artificial intelligence (AI) data centers, according to the Financial Times.

    And as PYMNTS reported last month, Apollo Global Management is working with five banks, including JPMorgan Chase & Co. and Goldman Sachs Group, to trade private credit.

    As the lines blur in financial services, and traditional banking players link with nonbanks to expand credit, so too is there a blurring of the nomenclature of those efforts, referred to variously as shadow banking or nonbank financial intermediation.

    Data found in this Monday (June 30) post by the St. Louis Federal Reserve underscore the magnitude of exposure. As measured at the end of the first quarter of 2025, U.S. banks held $1.14 trillion in loans outstanding to the nonbank financial sector.

    “This interconnectedness between banks and nonbanks adds an extra layer of intermediation, as banks lend to mortgage companies, insurance companies, investment funds (such as mutual funds, money market funds, hedge funds and private capital funds), pension funds, broker-dealers, securitization vehicles and other financial entities, which then lend directly to end users in the economy,” noted the Fed. The growth rate of non-depository financial institutional lending has grown by 26% on average each year since 2012.

    Getting a bit more granular, the Financial Stability Board estimated late last year that the aggregate FinTech lending across seven jurisdictions came in at $38.5 billion.

    As the FSB elaborated, “FinTech lending platforms can act as auxiliaries or intermediaries. As auxiliaries, they can be in the form of a ‘marketplace platform,’ which is an online market that allows lenders to trade directly with borrowers (peer-to-peer lending and crowdfunding platforms). Fintech lending platforms can act as intermediaries when they use their balance sheets to originate the lending.”

    Loans to mortgage and private credit intermediaries each represent 23% of loans outstanding, and loans to business intermediaries and consumer intermediaries represent 21% and 9%, respectively, estimated the Fed.

    Risks of ‘Runnable’ Activity

    In separate data and analysis as of last week, according to a report by the Congressional Research Service, “banks are increasingly lending to NBFIs (nonbank financial institutions) and, at the same time, reducing their lending to commercial and industrial borrowers.”

    “Increased lending from banks to NBFIs could expose banks to counterparty credit risk and spillover effects during a financial crisis…” the report added. “The size and growth of NBFI suggest that significant amount of financing is being intermediated and held outside of the banking sector. In contrast to the traditional banking model, where banks normally manage risks (e.g., credit, market, liquidity, and operational risks) on their balance sheets, the market-based NBFI financing model shifts risks toward capital markets investors and intermediaries.”

    As for the risks, the CRS cautioned that the “vulnerabilities affecting financial stability are present in capital markets NBFI, including in certain money-like instruments that face potential ‘runs,’ leverage levels, interconnectedness between nonbanks and banks, data and transparency issues, liquidity mismatch at certain open-end funds, and concentration risk at market intermediaries.”

    There’s a knock-on effect here, as some financial institutions are grappling with shadow banking stalwarts as competitors, which in turn has shifted activities away from core deposits toward long-term securities and other holdings. In this paper from economists at the Fed and at the University of Houston, there’s the contention that in doing so, net interest income margins are pressured.

    Continue Reading

  • Lundin Mining Announces Updated Share Capital, Provides Update on Share Buybacks and Announces Filing of ESTMA Report and Modern Slavery Report

    Lundin Mining Announces Updated Share Capital, Provides Update on Share Buybacks and Announces Filing of ESTMA Report and Modern Slavery Report

    Lundin Mining Announces Updated Share Capital, Provides Update on Share Buybacks and Announces Filing of ESTMA Report and Modern Slavery Report

    June 30, 2025

    VANCOUVER, BC, June 30, 2025 /CNW/ – (TSX: LUN) (Nasdaq Stockholm: LUMI) Lundin Mining Corporation (“Lundin Mining” or the “Company”) reports the following updated share capital and voting rights, in accordance with the Swedish Financial Instruments Trading Act. View PDF.

    The number of issued and outstanding shares of the Company has increased by 179,029 to 855,997,663 common shares with voting rights as of June 30, 2025. The increase in the number of issued and outstanding shares from May 31, 2025 to date is a result of the exercise of employee stock options or the vesting of employee share units. During this period, the Company did not purchase any shares for cancelation under its Normal Course Issuer Bid program.

    Normal Course Issuer Bid

    Under the Company’s shareholder distribution policy, the Company is committed to allocating up to US$150 million in annual share buybacks through the NCIB program. So far during 2025, Lundin Mining has acquired 12,629,000 common shares at a cost of approximately US$104 million.

    ESTMA Report and Modern Slavery Report

    Lundin Mining has filed its ESTMA Report and Modern Slavery Report for the year ended December 31, 2024, which can be found on the Company’s website (lundinmining.com).

    About Lundin Mining

    Lundin Mining is a diversified base metals mining company with operations or projects in Argentina, Brazil, Chile, and the United States of America, primarily producing copper, gold and nickel.

    The information in this release is subject to the disclosure requirements of Lundin Mining under the Swedish Financial Instruments Trading Act. The information was submitted for publication, through the agency of the contact persons set out below on June 30, 2025 at 16:00 Pacific Time.

    Lundin Mining Announces Updated Share Capital, Provides Update on Share Buybacks and Announces Filing of ESTMA Report and Modern Slavery Report (CNW Group/Lundin Mining Corporation)

    SOURCE Lundin Mining Corporation

    For further information, please contact: Stephen Williams, Vice President, Investor Relations: +1 604 806 3074; Robert Eriksson, Investor Relations Sweden: +46 8 440 54 50

    Continue Reading

  • Households’ subjective expectations: Disagreement, common drivers, and reaction to aggregate shocks

    Household expectations are usually thought to play a central role in the transmission of macroeconomic policy. Yet we still know too little about how households perceive and interpret the complex relationships and feedback between relevant economic variables that are at the core of general equilibrium. In a recent project (Ferreira and Pica 2025), we use new euro area household level survey data to show that households interpret contractionary demand and supply shocks as inflationary, contrary to conventional macroeconomic models. Our paper contributes to a recent literature investigating households’ mental models about economic relationships (e.g. André et al. 2022, Piccolo et al. 2025).

    The misalignment we uncover emerges consistently across time, countries, demographic groups, and levels of financial literacy. Although disagreement is pervasive, there is a clear structure in household expectations: two common factors explain a large share of the variation in beliefs within and across individual households in different countries.

    These patterns challenge standard assumptions in macroeconomic models and raise important questions about the communication and effectiveness of monetary policy. When central banks raise interest rates, they do so partly to influence expectations. However, if households’ understanding of and attention to transmission mechanisms differ from those assumed in the models that justify such rate changes – and if the households act on these beliefs – the impact of a policy may diverge from its intended effect. The links between expectations, real outcomes, and monetary policy has been explored in other Vox columns (e.g. Gorodnichenko et al. 2019, 2021, Weber et al. 2021).

    The effect of aggregate demand and supply shocks on expectations

    A natural way to explore the mental models that households entertain about economic dynamics is to evaluate the impact that exogenous shifts in demand and supply curves have on beliefs. Under rational expectations, these shifts should affect expectations about prices and quantities in a specific direction. We study how households in six major euro area economies – Belgium, France, Germany, Italy, the Netherlands, and Spain – respond to aggregate shocks using the ECB’s high-frequency Consumer Expectations Survey. This monthly panel captures detailed, household-level expectations about inflation, unemployment, interest rates, the general economic outlook, and other variables.

    Our first key finding is that contractionary monetary policy shocks raise inflation expectations. Specifically, following an ECB rate increase, households expect not only slower economic growth and higher unemployment, but also higher inflation over the next 12 months (Figure 1). This response is surprising. In textbook New Keynesian models, tighter monetary policy reduces demand and dampens inflation. Households’ expectations in our data move in the opposite direction and do so persistently. This result is in line with André et al. (2022) and Piccolo et al. (2025). One of our contributions to this literature is to validate these results internally across different identification strategies – including an event-study around ECB meetings – using alternative data sources going back to 2000. In addition, we show a surprising robustness across countries and demographic groups.

    Figure 1 Impulse responses of household expectations to a contractionary monetary policy shock

    Note: Impulse response functions of household expectations following a contractionary monetary surprise that raises the short rate by 25 basis points on impact. These responses are estimated using the panel local projections with Newey-West standard errors clustered at the monthly level. The 95% confidence intervals are shown in light blue; the 68% confidence intervals in dark blue. The estimation sample spans April 2020 to January 2024 for all variables except interest rate expectations, which are available from September 2020 onward.

    Turning to oil shocks, household-level responses align closely with the expected effects of a stagflationary shock: a rise in the real oil price leads to higher expected inflation while lowering expected economic growth (Figure 2).

    We therefore conclude that households consistently interpret contractionary supply and demand shocks as inflationary.

    Figure 2 Impulse responses of household expectations to a contractionary oil shock

    Notes: Impulse response functions of household expectations following a contractionary oil shock that raises the real oil price by 10% on impact. These responses are estimated using panel local projections with Newey-West standard errors clustered at the monthly level. The 95% confidence intervals are shown in light blue; the 68% confidence intervals in dark blue. The estimation sample spans April 2020 to June 2024 for all variables except interest rate expectations, which are available from September 2020 onward.

    Common drivers of beliefs

    Despite significant and persistent disagreement, household expectations move together in systematic ways. We uncover two latent drivers (principal components) that explain around 40% of the variation in expectations across households and countries.

    The first component reflects a broad perception that inflation is bad for the economy due, for example, to its origin on supply side shocks or to its erosion of disposable real incomes (Kamdar and Ray 2024, Binetti et al. 2024). Households that expect higher inflation also anticipate slower growth and weaker labour markets. This ‘inflation pessimism’ dominates the structure of expectations and suggests a mental model wherein price increases are interpreted as a sign of worsening real conditions.

    The second component captures concerns about interest rates and unemployment. Households that expect higher interest rates also expect weaker economic outcomes, suggesting that they associate rate hikes with cost increases and labour market deterioration, rather than with disinflationary effects.

    Strikingly, these latent drivers are not systematically linked to observable characteristics like age, education, housing tenure, or financial literacy. Nor are they specific to any one country. This points to a shared cognitive framework – a simplified but common view of the business cycle – that shapes how households interpret macroeconomic developments.

    Building on this, we estimate a two-factor structure for the cross-section of all expectations. The structure is general enough to capture individual time-invariant biases and disturbances, and can be mapped onto most equilibrium models with a generalised expectation formation process. The first factor, which explains the bulk of the time-series variation, tracks inflation-related sentiment potentially emerging from attention to media outlets, including the supply bottlenecks of 2021, the energy crisis, and ECB rate hikes from mid-2022 onward. The second factor correlates closely with unemployment dynamics, suggesting that demand-side perceptions are linked primarily to real activity (Figure 3).

    Figure 3 Evolution of identified factors over the sample period

    Note: Figure plots factors identified through sign restrictions on household expectations data; sample covers the period from September 2020 to December 2024. The two thick lines represent the optimal uncorrelated factors, identified using a standard Euclidean metric. The thinner lines show the 10th, 25th, 50th, 75th, and 90th percentiles of the distribution of distances for alternative valid models (i.e. rotations). Blue lines correspond to the first factor, identified by loadings that capture opposite correlations between expected economic growth and expected inflation. Red lines correspond to the second factor, identified based on demand-type signs on expected economic growth and expected inflation. Vertical solid lines mark key events: (1) disruptions in the Suez and Panama Canals (May 2021), (2) the Russian invasion of Ukraine (February 2022), and (3) the ECB’s first post-pandemic interest rate hike (July 2022).

    Conclusions and implications for policy

    Understanding how households interpret macroeconomic policy is vital for the effectiveness of central bank action. Our study shows that households often react in ways that contradict the standard theoretical playbook. This misalignment is systematic and rooted in a shared structure of beliefs, not idiosyncratic noise.

    These findings have important implications. If households believe that contractionary monetary policy fuels rather than curbs inflation, then standard policy levers may be less effective than models suggest. Communication strategies that rely on rational expectations may fall flat if the public’s mental model of the economy diverges fundamentally from that of policymakers.

    Moreover, if inflation expectations are not anchored by policy signals but are instead shaped by perceived cost pressures, there is a risk of self-fulfilling inflation dynamics. Policymakers may inadvertently reinforce inflation fears if rate hikes are seen as signs of economic trouble rather than tools to stabilise prices.

    Our evidence suggests that households interpret shocks through a lens shaped by recent crises – such as the energy shock following Russia’s invasion of Ukraine – and by deep-rooted concerns about real purchasing power. Addressing these perceptions may require more than technical briefings or forecasts. Clear, relatable narratives about how policy affects inflation and the broader economy are essential.

    References

    Andre, P, C Pizzinelli, C Roth and J Wohlfart (2022), “Subjective Models of the Macroeconomy: Evidence from Experts and Representative Samples”, Review of Economic Studies 86(6): 2958–91.

    Binetti, A, F Nuzzi and S Stantcheva (2024), “People’s understanding of inflation”, Journal of Monetary Economics 148, 103652.

    Coibion, O, Y Gorodnichenko and M Weber (2022), “Monetary Policy Communications and Their Effects on Household Inflation Expectations”, Journal of Political Economy 130(6): 1537–84.

    Ferreira, C and S Pica (2005), “Households’ Subjective Expectations: Disagreement, Common Drivers, and Reaction to Monetary Policy”, Banco de Espana Working Paper No. 2445.

    Gorodnichenko, Y, M Weber and O Coibion (2019), “Monetary policy communications and their effects on household inflation expectations”, VoxEU.org, 22 February.

    Gorodnichenko, Y, M Weber and O Coibion (2021), “How inflation expectations affect households’ spending decisions”, VoxEU.org, 19 March.

    Kamdar, R and W Ray (2024), “Attention-Driven Sentiment and the Business Cycle”, University of Oxford Working Paper.

    Piccolo, J, A Russo, E Granziera and E Castelnuovo (2025), “Households’ Macroeconomic Beliefs: The Role of Education”, Marco Fanno Working Paper 316, Universita Degli Studi di Padova.

    Weber, M, G Kenny, D Georgarakos, Y Gorodnichenko and O Coibion (2021), “The effect of macroeconomic uncertainty on household spending”, VoxEU.org, 31 July.

    Continue Reading